by Steve McDaniel and Jon Hurt,
Contributing Editors
Maybe that’s a little harsh. But, that indeed WAS the punish- ment exacted by Chinese emperors for several thousand years upon
anyone caught attempting to export
Bombyx mori (silkworms) or mulberry
seeds (Morus alba) in order to start international silkworm competition (
sericulture). But, sericulture reached Korea
around 200 BC, when waves of Chinese
immigrants arrived there.
Silk reached the West through a number of different channels. Shortly after
AD 300, sericulture traveled westward
and the cultivation of the silkworm was
established in India. Stories are also told
how, in AD 440, a Khotan prince (
today’s Hetian, a kingdom on the rim of
Taklamakan desert) courted and won a
Chinese princess. The princess smuggled
out silkworm eggs by hiding them in
her voluminous hairpiece - then Khotan
kept the secret too (why share it with the
Westerners and kill a good market.
Then around AD 550, two Nestorian
monks appeared at the Byzantine
Emperor Justinian’s court with silkworm eggs hidden in the hollow bamboo staves they carried (sneaky, but
hardly original). The Byzantine church
created imperial workshops, monopolizing production-again keeping the
secret to themselves. This allowed a
silk industry to be established in the
Middle East, undercutting the market
for ordinary-grade Chinese silk. By
the sixth century the Persians, too, had
mastered the art of silk weaving, developing their own rich textile artistry. It
was only around the time of the Second
Crusades 13th Century) that Italy began silk production with the introduction of 2000 skilled silk weavers from
Constantinople. Eventually silk production became widespread in Europe.
So it goes with trade secrets – they
are only as good as your ability to keep
them a secret! But, several thousand
years? Dadgummit! That beats Coca
Cola’s allegedly-deeply-vaulted and highly-vaunt-ed secret formula by at
least a couple of millennia.
It goes to show you though
that protection of trade secrets on an international
scale has been with us for
a VERY long time.
Ratchet quickly forward to the present times.
Just as is the case between
states in the U.S., trade
secret laws range all over
the place internationally.
The likely reason for this
disharmony is, of course,
money. Filing a patent
gives a government an opportunity to charge patent fees for virtually every
contact with a patent office. Naturally, this was a
model that had a built in
incentive that inspired nations across the world to
adopt and harmonize laws
and procedures globally. In
contrast, a trade secret is,
at its core, simply maintaining information as confidential. And governments
can’t easily charge a fee on
what they don’t know exists. Hence, laws protecting trade secrets have been
slower to standardize between jurisdictions, though the trend to
smooth out differences is clearly visible.
In the United States, trade secrets
have historically been protected by in-
dividual state common laws. This made
seeking legal regress for misappropria-
tion a more costly proposition given the
use of multiple lawyers familiar with
different local statutes. However, af-
ter a couple centuries the U.S. started
to get its act together with the publi-
cation of the Uniform Trade Secrets
Act in 1979. After a few decades, some
form of this act has now been made the
statute in 47 states. Adoption is pend-
ing in Massachusetts, with New York
and North Carolina being the remaining
holdouts. Is the same trend happening
elsewhere in the World? It would appear
to be so.
Appropriate Punishment for Theft
of Trade Secrets - Death by Beheading